Fiscal and macroprudential policies in a monetary union

  1. José E. Boscá 1
  2. Javier Ferri 1
  3. Margarita Rubio 2
  1. 1 Universitat de València
    info

    Universitat de València

    Valencia, España

    ROR https://ror.org/043nxc105

  2. 2 University of Nottingham
    info

    University of Nottingham

    Nottingham, Reino Unido

    ROR https://ror.org/01ee9ar58

Revista:
Documentos de trabajo ( FEDEA )

ISSN: 1696-7496

Año de publicación: 2022

Número: 8

Páginas: 1-46

Tipo: Documento de Trabajo

Otras publicaciones en: Documentos de trabajo ( FEDEA )

Resumen

In the European Monetary Union (EMU), monetary policy is decided by the European Central Bank (ECB). This can create some imbalances that can potentially be corrected by national policies. So far, Öscal policy was the natural candidate to adjust those imbalances. Nevertheless, after the global Önancial crisis (GFC), a new policy candidate has emerged, namely national macroprudential policies, with the mission of reducing Önancial risks. This issue gives rise to an interesting research question: how do macroprudential and Öscal policies interact? By a§ecting real interest rates and the level of activity, a discretionary macroprudential policy alters the evolution of public debt and can impose a Öscal cost when the government is forced to increase tax rates to stabilize the public debt-to-GDP ratio. In a monetary union, a domestic macroprudential shock creates substantial cross- border Önancial e§ects and also ináuences the foreign country Öscal stance. Moreover, a discretionary government spending policy a§ects housing prices, so the strenght with which macroprudential policy reacts to a change in the price of houses has an impact on the Öscal multiplier.

Referencias bibliográficas

  • Beetsma R. and H. Jensen (2005), "Monetary and fiscal policy interactions in a micro-founded model of a monetary union", Journal of International Economics, 67(2), 320-352.
  • Blagov, B. (2013), "Financial crises and time-varying risk premia in a small open economy: a Markov-Switching DSGE model for Estonia," Bank of Estonia WP2013-8.
  • Bonam D. and J. Lukkezen (2019), "Fiscal and monetary policy coordination, macroeconomic stability, and sovereign risk premia", Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 51 (2-3), 581-616.
  • Bussière, M., Cao, J., de Haan, J., Hills, R., Lloyd. S., Meunier, B., Pedrono, J. Reinhardt, D., Sinha, S., Sowerbutts, R. and Konstantin Styrin (2020), "The interaction between macroprudential policy and monetary policy: Overview", Review of International Economics, DOI: 10.1111/roie.12505
  • Calvo, G.A. (1983), "Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework," Journal of Monetary Economics, 12 (3), 383-398.
  • Casares, M. and J. Vázquez (2018), "Why are labor markets in Spain and Germany so di¤erent?," Economic Modelling, 75 (C), 320-335.
  • Clarida, R., Gali, J. and M. Gertler (1999), "The science of monetary policy: a new Keynesian perspective", Journal of Economic Literature, 3 (4), 1661–1707.
  • Clarida, R., J. Galí and M. Gertler (2000), "Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: evidence and some theory," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 147-180.
  • Deloitte (2016), "Overview of European Residential Market," Property Index, 5th edition, July.
  • De Walque, G., Smets, F. and R. Wouters (2005), "An estimated two-country DSGE model for the Euro area and the US economy," European Central Bank, mimeo.
  • Demid E. (2018), "Fiscal and monetary policy: coordination or conflict?", International Economic Journal, 32(4), 547-571.
  • Deutsche Bundesbank (2017), "Mark-ups of firms in selected European countries," Monthly Report, December, 53.
  • Engel, C. and A. Matsumoto (2006), "Portfolio choice in a monetary open-economy DSGE model," National Bureau of Economic Research.
  • Farhi, E. and I. Werning (2016), "A theory of macroprudential policies in the presence of nominal rigidities", Econometrica, 84, 1645-1704.
  • Farhi, E. and I. Werning (2017), "Fiscal Unions", American Economic Review, 107(12), 3788-834.
  • Ferrero, A. (2009), "Fiscal and Monetary Rules for a Currency Union", Journal of International Economics, 77 (1), 1-10.
  • European Commission (2018), Quarterly Report on the Euro Area, 17, 4, Ch I.
  • Galí, J. and M. Gertler (2007), "Macroeconomic modeling for monetary policy evaluation," Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21 (4), 25-46.
  • Gali, J. and T. Monacelli (2005), "Monetary policy and exchange rate volatility in a small open economy," The Review of Economic Studies, 72 (3), 707-734.
  • Galí, J, López-Salido, D. and J. Vallés (2004), "Rule-of-Thumb Consumers and the Design of Interest Rate Rules," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 36 (4), 739-763.
  • Hansen, G.D. and S. ·Imrohoglu, S. (2016), "Fiscal reform and government debt in Japan: A neoclassical perspective," Review of Economic Dynamics, 21, 201-224.
  • Iacoviello, M. (2005), "House prices, borrowing constraints, and monetary policy in the business cycle," American Economic Review, 95 (3), 739-764.
  • IMF (2017), "Greece: Request for Stand-By Arrangement", Press Release, Sta¤ Report, and State- ment by the Executive Director for Greece.
  • Kolasa, M. (2009), "Structural heterogeneity or asymmetric shocks? Poland and the euro area through the lens of a two-country DSGE model," Economic Modelling, 26 (6), 1245-1269.
  • Krishnamurthy, A. and A. Vissing-Jorgensen (2015), "The Impact of Treasury Supply on Financial Sector Lending and Stability," Journal of Financial Economics, 118 (3), 571-600.
  • Leeper, E. (1991), "Equilibria under "active"and "passive" monetary and "fiscal policies", Journal of Monetary Economics, 27(1), 129-147.
  • Malmierka, M. (2022), "Stabilization and the policy mix in a monetary union", The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 83, 92-118.
  • McCallum, B. (2001), "Should Monetary Policy Respond Strongly To Output Gaps?," American Economic Review, 91 (2), 258-262.
  • Monacelli, T. (2009), "New Keynesian models, durable goods, and collateral constraints," Journal of Monetary Economics, 56 (2), 242-254.
  • Monacelli, T. (2008), "Optimal monetary policy with collateralized household debt and borrowing constraints," NBER Chapters, in: Asset Prices and Monetary Policy, 103-146.
  • Ratto, M., Roeger, W. and J. in´t Veld (2009), "QUEST III: An estimated open-economy DSGE model of the euro area with fiscal and monetary policy," Economic Modelling, 26 (1), 222-233.
  • Reis, R. (2020), "The Fiscal Footprint of Macroprudential Policy," LSE unpublished manuscript.
  • Rubio, M (2014), "Housing-market heterogeneity in a monetary union," Journal of International Money and Finance, 40, 163-184.
  • Sargent, T.J. (2009), "Dynamic macroeconomic theory," Harvard University Press.
  • Sargent, T.J. (1987), "Macroeconomic theory," Academic Press New York.
  • Sauer, S. and J. E. Sturm (2007), "Using Taylor Rules toUnderstand European Central Bank Monetary Policy," German Economic Review, 8 (3), 375-398.
  • Schmitt-Grohé, S. and M. Uribe (2003), "Closing small open economy models," Journal of Inter- national Economics, 61 (1), 163-185.
  • Solow, R. (2010), "Prepared Statement Robert Solow Professor Emeritus, House Committee on Science and Technology Subcommittee on Investigations and Oversight," Building a Science of Economics for the Real World, 20.
  • Stähler, N. and C. Thomas (2012), "FiMod A DSGE model for fiscal policy simulations," Economic Modelling, 29 (2), 239-261.
  • Yun, T. (2011), "Transmission mechanisms of the public debt," Manuscript, Seoul Na.
  • Westig, D. and C. Bertalot (2017), "Hypostat 2017: A Review of Europes Mortgage and Housing Markets," European Mortgage Federation