The timing of environmental policy in a duopolistic market

  1. Rafael Moner-Colonques
  2. Santiago J. Rubio
Zeitschrift:
Economía agraria y recursos naturales

ISSN: 1578-0732

Datum der Publikation: 2015

Ausgabe: 15

Nummer: 1

Seiten: 11-40

Art: Artikel

DOI: 10.7201/EARN.2015.01.02 DIALNET GOOGLE SCHOLAR lock_openDialnet editor

Andere Publikationen in: Economía agraria y recursos naturales

Zusammenfassung

In this paper the strategic use of innovation by two polluting firms to influence environmental policy is evaluated. The analysis is carried out by comparing two alternative policy regimes for two policy instruments: Taxes and standards. The first of the regimes assumes that the regulator commits to an ex-ante level of the policy instrument. In the second one, there is no commitment. The results show that when there is no commitment and a tax is used to control emissions, the strategic behavior of firms can be welfare improving if the efficiency of the clean technology is relatively low. If this is not the case, the strategic behavior of the duopolists has a detrimental effect on welfare regardless of the policy instrument used to control emissions.

Informationen zur Finanzierung

Acknowledgements: The authors would like to thank two anonymous referees and Francisco André for their comments. The usual disclaimer applies. We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Spanish Ministry of Economics and Competitiveness under project ECO2013-45045-R, and Generalitat Valenciana under project PROMETEO/2014 /Fase II.

Geldgeber

Bibliographische Referenzen

  • Antelo, M. and Loureiro, M.L. (2009). "Asymmetric information, signaling and environmental taxes in oligopoly". Ecological Economics, 68(5): 1430-1440. http://doi.org/bg3bk8.
  • Bonroy, O. and Constantatos, Ch. (2015). "On the economics of labels: how their introduction affects the functioning of markets and the welfare of all participants". American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 97(1): 239-259. http://doi.org/3z4.
  • Carlsson, F. (2000). "Environmental taxation and strategic commitment in duopoly models". Environmental and Resource Economics, 15(3): 243-256. http://doi.org/dbvj5b.
  • Chiou, J.R. and Hu, J.L. (2001). "Environmental research joint ventures under emission taxes". Environmental and Resource Economics, 20(2): 129-146. http://doi.org/btfcmc.
  • Coria, J. (2009). "Taxes, permits, and the diffusion of a new technology". Resource and Energy Economics, 31(4): 249-271. http://doi.org/fq8w69.
  • Damania, D. (1996). "Pollution taxes and pollution abatement in an oligopoly supergame". Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 30(3): 323-336. http://doi.org/dkpvrv.
  • David, M. and Sinclair-Desgagné, B. (2005). "Environmental regulation and the eco-industry". Journal of Regulatory Economics 28(2): 141-155. http://doi.org/cqfsgj.
  • Denicolò, V. (1999). "Pollution-reducing innovations under taxes or permits". Oxford Economic Papers, 51(1): 184-199. http://doi.org/df9pv6.
  • Gersbach, H. and Glazer, A. (1999). "Markets and regulatory hold-up problems". Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 37(2): 151-164. http://doi.org/c9zf4d.
  • Gil-Moltó, M.J. and Varvarigos, D. (2013). "Emission taxes and the adoption of cleaner technologies: The case of environmentally conscious consumers". Resource and Energy Economics, 35(4): 486-504. http://doi.org/3zz.
  • Innes, R. and Bial, J.J. (2002). "Inducing innovation in the environmental technology of oligopolistic firms". Journal of Industrial Economics, 50(3): 265-287. http://doi.org/btdtp7.
  • Jakob, M. and Brunner, S. (2014). "Optimal commitment under uncertainty: Adjustment rules for climate policy". Strategic Behavior and the Environment, 4: 291-310. http://doi.org/3z7.
  • James, C. (2014). Global status of commercialized biotech/GM crops: 2014. ISAAA Brief No. 49. ISAAA. Ithaca, NY.
  • Katsoulacos, Y. and Xepapadeas, A. (1995). "Environmental policy under oligopoly with endogenous market structure". The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 97(3): 411-420. http://doi.org/bmf2ms.
  • Katsoulacos, Y. and Xepapadeas, A. (1996). "Environmental innovation, spillovers and optimal policy rules". In Carraro, C., Katsoulacos, Y. and A. Xepapadeas (Eds.): Environmental Policy and Market Structure, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht:143-150.
  • Laffont, J.J. and Tirole, J. (1996). "Pollution permits and environmental innovation". Journal of Public Economics, 62(1-2): 127-140. http://doi.org/cc2kf2.
  • McDonald, S. and Poyago-Theotoky, J. (2014). "Green technology and optimal emissions taxation". Nota di Lavoro 59.2014, FEEM. Available at SSRN: http://doi.org/3z8.
  • Moner-Colonques, R. and Rubio, S.J. (2014). The strategic use of innovation to influence environmental policy: Taxes versus standards. Typescript, Department of Economic Analysis, University of Valencia.
  • Montero, J.P. (2002). "Permits, standards, and technology innovation". Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 44(1): 23-44. http://doi.org/dh75ch.
  • Montero, J.P. (2011). "A note on environmental policy and innovation when govern-governments cannot commit". Energy Economics, 33: S13-S19. http://doi.org/dzx48r.
  • Ouchida, Y. and Goto, D. (2014). "Environmental research joint ventures and time-consistent emission tax". FEEM Working Paper No. 35.2014. Available at SSRN: http://doi.org/32b.
  • Petrakis, E. and Xepapadeas, A. (1999). "Does government precommitment promote environmental innovation?" In Petrakis, E., Sartzetakis, E. and Xepapadeas, A. (Eds.): Environmental Regulation and Market Power, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham: 145-161.
  • Petrakis, E. and Xepapadeas, A. (2001). To commit or not to commit: Environmental policy in imperfectly competitive markets. Typescript, Department of Economics, University of Crete.
  • Petrakis, E. and Xepapadeas, A. (2003). "Location decisions of a polluting firm and the time consistency of environmental policy". Resource and Energy Economics, 25(2): 197-214. http://doi.org/dmqn2m.
  • Poyago-Theotoky, J. and Teerasuwannajak, K. (2002). "The timing of environmental policy: A note on the role of product differentiation". Journal of Regulatory Economics, 21(3): 305-316. http://doi.org/ffk94z.
  • Poyago-Theotoky, J. (2007). "The organization of R&D and environmental policy". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 62(1): 63-75. http://doi.org/fv6s2x.
  • Poyago-Theotoky, J. (2010). "Corrigendum to 'The organization of R&D and environmental policy' [J. Econ. Behav. Org. 62(1) 2007: 63-75]". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 76(2): 449. http://doi.org/fk4ktp.
  • Puller, S.L. (2006) "The strategic use of innovation to influence regulatory standards". Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 52(3): 690-706. http://doi.org/ftwnp7.
  • Requate, T. (2005). "Timing and commitment of environmental policy, adoption of new technology, and repercussions on R&D". Environmental and Resource Economics, 31(2): 175-199. http://doi.org/ccmpbg.
  • Requate, T. (2006). "Environmental policy under imperfect competition: A survey". In Tietenberg, T. and Folmer, H. (Eds.): The International Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Economics 2006/07, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham: 120-207.
  • Ulph, A. (1996). "Environmental policy and international trade when governments and producers act strategically". Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 30(3): 265-281. http://doi.org/fm3qq6.
  • Ulph, A. and Ulph, D. (2013). "Optimal climate change policies when governments cannot commit". Environmental and Resource Economics, 56(2): 161-176. http://doi.org/32f.
  • Wirl, F. (2014). "Taxes versus permits as incentive for the intertemporal supply of a clean technology by a monopoly". Resource and Energy Economics, 36(1): 248-269. http://doi.org/32g.